...
首页> 外文期刊>Journal of commercial biotechnology >Intellectual property and biotechnology innovation: To protect or not protect?
【24h】

Intellectual property and biotechnology innovation: To protect or not protect?

机译:知识产权与生物技术创新:保护还是不保护?

获取原文
           

摘要

The intellectual property protection differences between countries is a contentious issue. Countries with strong innovation systems (technology producers) often favor strong intellectual property protection because it motivates innovation by granting innovators temporary market exclusivity for their new, nonobvious and useful inventions; countries with less-developed innovation systems (technology consumers) often prefer weaker patent protection, as it enables them to access inventions developed elsewhere without having to pay licensing or manufacturing fees that may be beyond their capacity (or desire) to pay. Although the World Trade Organization's TRIPS agreement does provide governments the right to use patented technologies without authorization, this compulsory licensing is limited to cases of a€?national emergency or other circumstances of extreme urgencya€?. Furthermore, there is often disagreement on what constitutes a national emergency or circumstance of extreme urgency. The central question underlying TRIPS claims or unauthorized use of patents is that of their greater impact on a country's industry and economy. A common rationale for unlicensed patent use is that improving their citizen's health is a national priority, so governments ought to produce high-value drugs domestically, without license if necessary, to serve their national interests. Price controls can be seen as a less-extreme version of unlicensed use as, instead of denying innovators profits from domestic sales, price controls give governments greater power in dictating terms. The downside of these strategies, however, is that they can deprive countries of patented technologies; several years ago AstraZeneca responded to pressures from the New Zealand government to lower prices for Zoladex by announcing that they would simply stop selling the drug in that market. Domestic industries can also be affected; Novartis recently bypassed the appeals courts in India and responded to the Indian patent office's decision not to grant its patent for Glivec (sold as Gleevec in the United States) by announcing that it would redirect hundreds of millions of dollars of R&D investments to other countries. India and New Zealand are not alone. There are plenty of other examples of drug companies threatening to withdraw drugs or R&D investments from other developed and developing countries. The common theme in these battles is that these decisions can have broader impacts than the individual products or patents involved. While licensing decisions are often based on individual drugs or individual diseases, they can signal to companies that a given country represents a poor market and can discourage a company from domestic R&D investments or developing of drugs for endemic conditions. The result is that near-term benefits are exchanged for long-term deficits. Although simple logic suggests that all countries a€“ developing and developed a€“ should offer the strongest intellectual property protection possible, that solution is rarely practical for economic reasons, and it deprives government-backed health-care systems a valuable bargaining tool. So, the battle between countries and drug manufacturers will likely continue, using patents, price controls, R&D investment and other levers. What is of particular interest is how the dynamics change as countries transition from being technology consumers to technology producers (or, possibly, the reverse). As countries that were once broad technology consumers develop technology-innovation capacity and find it increasingly favorable to strengthen their patent laws, how can they strengthen these laws while protecting legacy companies and their domestic interests in areas in which they are still net technology consumers? Additionally, as low wage-cost countries face competition from each other, how can they motivate foreign investment in a way that promotes the growth of domestic companies? Furthermore, how much leverage can countries with large markets wield?
机译:国家之间的知识产权保护差异是一个有争议的问题。拥有强大创新体系的国家(技术生产者)通常倾向于强有力的知识产权保护,因为它通过授予创新者对其新的,非显而易见的和有用的发明暂时的市场独占权来激励创新。创新系统欠发达的国家(技术消费者)通常更喜欢较弱的专利保护,因为它使他们能够获得在其他地方开发的发明,而不必支付可能超出其支付能力(或意愿)的许可或制造费用。尽管世界贸易组织的TRIPS协议确实为政府提供了未经授权使用专利技术的权利,但这种强制许可仅限于国家紧急情况或其他极端紧急情况。此外,在什么构成国家紧急状态或极端紧急情况下常常存在分歧。 TRIPS索赔或未经授权使用专利的核心问题是专利对一个国家的工业和经济的更大影响。无牌使用专利的一个普遍理由是,改善公民的健康是国家的优先事项,因此,各国政府应在国内生产高价值的药物,必要时无需许可即可为其国家利益服务。价格控制可以看作是无执照使用的一种极端形式,因为价格控制并没有剥夺创新者从国内销售中获得的利润,反而赋予了政府更大的决定权。但是,这些策略的缺点是它们会剥夺各国专利技术;几年前,阿斯利康(AstraZeneca)宣布将停止在该市场销售该药物,以此回应新西兰政府降低Zoladex价格的压力。国内产业也可能受到影响;诺华(Novartis)最近绕开了印度的上诉法院,并回应了印度专利局关于不授予其Glivec专利(在美国以Gleevec出售)的决定的决定,宣布将将数亿美元的研发投资重定向到其他国家。印度和新西兰并不孤单。制药公司还有许多其他例子威胁要从其他发达国家和发展中国家撤回药品或进行研发投资。这些斗争的共同主题是,这些决定可能比所涉及的单个产品或专利具有更广泛的影响。尽管许可决策通常基于个别药物或个别疾病,但它们可以向公司发出信号,即给定国家/地区代表市场不佳,并且可能阻止公司进行国内研发投资或针对地方性疾病开发药品。结果是将短期利益与长期赤字交换。尽管简单的逻辑表明,所有“正在开发和发展中的国家”都应提供尽可能强大的知识产权保护,但是由于经济原因,该解决方案很少实用,并且剥夺了政府支持的医疗体系的宝贵议价工具。因此,利用专利,价格控制,研发投资和其他手段,国家与药品制造商之间的战斗可能会继续。特别令人感兴趣的是,随着国家从技术消费者过渡到技术生产者(或者可能是相反的情况),这种动态变化如何。随着曾经是广泛技术消费者的国家发展技术创新能力并发现加强其专利法变得越来越有利,它们如何才能在加强其法律保护的同时又保护传统公司及其仍是净技术消费者领域的国内利益的法律呢?此外,当低工资成本的国家彼此竞争时,它们如何以促进国内公司增长的方式来激励外国投资?此外,拥有大型市场的国家可以利用多少杠杆?

著录项

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号