首页> 外文会议>IAEE International Conference;International Association for Energy Economics >CROSS SUBSIDIES ACROSS NETWORK USERS: RENEWABLE SELFCONSUMPTION
【24h】

CROSS SUBSIDIES ACROSS NETWORK USERS: RENEWABLE SELFCONSUMPTION

机译:跨网络用户的交叉补贴:可再生的自我消费

获取原文

摘要

OverviewTo decrease the greenhouse gases from the electricity sector, policy-makers promoted photovoltaic (PV) technologywith public supports. These supports led to a fast development of this technology and a significant decrease of thePV generation costs. Currently, some developed countries have reached the grid parity, which means that the PVgeneration cost is equal to the cost of the electricity withdrawal from the grid. When the grid parity is achieved, selfconsumptionbecomes profitable and public supports are no longer needed. In France, the self-consumers are stillincipients but they represent 36% of PV installations in 2016. The development of so called prosumers (a term torefer to people who both produce and consume) is not longer driven by direct supports but they benefit of indirectincentivizing such as the savings on the grid rate. Indeed, the grid rate is based mainly on a volumetric component inFrance but also in Europe (AF-Mercados, 2015). This indirect support raises a lot of concerns since decentralizedgeneration may induce cross-subsidies from consumers to prosumers (Eid et al, 2014; Picciariello et al, 2015;Simshauser 2016). Indeed, the grid operators face a financial deficit because of the decrease in the volume ofelectricity withdrawal whereas their costs are mainly based of fixed costs (Felder et al, 2014; Perez, 2016). In thissituation, grid operators have to increase the grid rate in order to balance their financial account. The cost of directpublic supports decreases with the development of self-consumption but it maybe offset by the increase of thenetwork tariff. This issue is leading the French regulator to set a special grid rate for prosumers.In this article, a methodology to estimate the volume of self-consumption in France with a half-hour time step ispresented. By applying the current Time-of-Use grid tariff, we computed the cross-subsidies from 2018 to 2021 fordifferent customer profiles. This time frame corresponds to the current regulation for French grid operators. Then weinvestigated some rate-settings to avoid these cross-subsidies. Without changing the rate structure, cross-subsidieswill represent less than 1€ for households and 3€ for firms in 2021.This paper contributes to the cross-subsidies literature and gives insights to the decision-making by identifying theindirect cost for ratepayers links with the self-consumption development and the grid rate structure. Indeed, the paperintroduces a new methodology to estimate self-consumption on a macro level in a short time step of 30 min withpublic data. Then, we compute the financial impact of the development of self-consumption for ratepayers withdifferent grid rate structures.MethodsWith the coefficient of profiles provided by the main French distribution grid operator (which is called Enedis inFrance and manages 95% of the French grid), average load consumption and generation curves are estimated fordifferent customer profiles by half-hour time steps. These load curves allow us to compute the amount of selfconsumptionfrom 2018 to 2021 by season. The development of PV capacities corresponds to the Frenchgovernment’s goals. We apply the current Time-of-Use rate for each prosumer based on a peak and an off-peak tariffwhich varies depending on the seasons. By applying corresponding rates acoording to different seasons, financialdeficit is estimated for the grid operator. Then, his financial account is balanced by increasing the fixed charge forthe self-consumers. We compute the amount of cross-subsidies for each average customer profile for each year.Finally, different rate structures are tested in order to avoid cross-subsidies.ResultsResults show that 93% of the PV self-consumption occurs in peak-time and represents 95% of the cross-subsidies.Electricity self-consumption is higher in summer (68%) but the cross-subsidies are more significant in winter.Indeed, 54% of cross-subsidies occur in winter because the grid rate is higher in winter than in summer so the priceeffect is more prominent than the volume effect. Nevertheless, cross-subsidies represent less than 1€ in 2021 forresidential customers and 3€ for firms because PV self-consumption represents 0.27% of the national consumption.In order to avoid cross-subsidies, the structure of the grid rate needs to be changed. We show the self-consumers arewilling to pay an annual fee to finance the grid than pay the value of lost load.ConclusionsThis paper provides a new methodology to estimate the amount of self-consumption across seasons. We presentquantified results on the impact of the development of self-consumption on the income of the grid operators. In 2021,cross-subsidies will be low because the amount of self-consumption represents less than 1% of the nationalconsumption. However, a grid rate based on a volumetric charge is maybe no longer suitable especially forprosumers. Regulators need to take account of this parameter to implement specific grid rate for prosumers. Theyhave to investigate the correlation between the amount of self-consumption and the cost of grid operators at eachhour. One way is to increase the part of the fixed charge.
机译:概述 为了减少电力部门的温室气体排放,政策制定者推广了光伏(PV)技术 在公众的支持下。这些支持导致了这项技术的快速发展,并且大大减少了 光伏发电成本。目前,一些发达国家已经达到电网平价,这意味着光伏发电 发电成本等于从电网取电的成本。当达到电网平价时,自耗 变得有利可图,不再需要公共支持。在法国,自给自足的人仍然 初期,但在2016年占光伏装置的36%。所谓的生产者的发展(指 指既生产又消费的人)不再受到直接支持的驱动,但他们受益于间接支持 激励措施,例如节省电网费用。实际上,网格速率主要基于 法国,但在欧洲也是如此(AF-Mercados,2015年)。自分散以来,这种间接支持引起了很多关注 代可能会引起消费者对生产者的交叉补贴(Eid等人,2014; Picciariello等人,2015; Simshauser 2016)。确实,电网运营商面临财务赤字,原因是发电量的减少。 取电的成本主要基于固定成本(Felder等,2014; Perez,2016)。在这个 在这种情况下,电网运营商必须提高电网费率以平衡其财务帐户。费用直接 公众支持随着自我消费的发展而减少,但它可能被自我消费的增加所抵消。 网络资费。这个问题导致法国监管机构为生产者设定了特殊的电网费率。 在本文中,用半小时的时间步长估算法国的自我消费量的方法是 提出了。通过应用当前的分时电价,我们计算了2018年至2021年的交叉补贴 不同的客户资料。此时间范围符合法国电网运营商的现行法规。然后我们 调查了一些费率设置以避免这些交叉补贴。在不改变费率结构的情况下,交叉补贴 到2021年,对于家庭而言,这将不足1欧元,对于企业而言,将不到3欧元。 本文为交叉补贴文献做出了贡献,并通过确定哪些因素为决策提供了见解。 纳税人的间接成本与自我消费发展和电网费率结构相关。确实,这篇论文 引入了一种新的方法,可以在30分钟的短时间内逐步在宏观水平上估算自我消费, 公开数据。然后,我们计算了自付费用对纳税人的财务影响 不同的网格速率结构。 方法 由主要的法国配电网运营商(在印度称为Enedis)提供的配置文件系数 法国,并管理着法国95%的电网),估算的平均负荷消耗和发电曲线为 通过半小时的时间步长获得不同的客户资料。这些负载曲线使我们能够计算自耗量 从2018年到2021年(按季节)。光伏能力的发展与法国 政府的目标。我们根据峰值和非峰值资费应用每个生产者的当前使用时间率 因季节而异。通过根据不同季节应用相应的费率,财务 估计电网运营商的赤字。然后,通过增加固定费用来平衡他的财务帐户 自我消费。我们计算每年每个平均客户资料的交叉补贴数量。 最后,为了避免交叉补贴,对不同的费率结构进行了测试。 结果 结果显示93%的PV自耗发生在高峰时间,代表了95%的交叉补贴。 夏季的电力自耗较高(68%),但冬季的交叉补贴更为明显。 确实,冬季有54%的交叉补贴是因为冬季的电网费率比夏季高,因此价格 效果比音量效果更突出。尽管如此,2021年的交叉补贴不足1欧元 居民用户和3欧元的公司,因为光伏自耗占全国消费的0.27%。 为了避免交叉补贴,需要更改电网费率的结构。我们显示出自消费者是 愿意支付年费以资助电网,而不是支付损失的负载值。 结论 本文提供了一种新的方法来估算各个季节的自我消费量。我们提出 自我消费发展对电网运营商收入的影响的量化结果。在2021年, 交叉补贴将很低,因为自我消费的金额不到全国的1% 消耗。然而,基于体积电荷的网格速率可能不再适用,尤其是对于 生产者。监管机构需要考虑此参数,才能为生产者实现特定的电网费率。他们 必须研究每次的自耗量与电网运营商成本之间的相关性 小时。一种方法是增加固定费用的一部分。

著录项

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号