首页> 外文会议> >CROSS-SUBSIDIES IN ENERGY COOPERATIVE TARIFF DESIGNS
【24h】

CROSS-SUBSIDIES IN ENERGY COOPERATIVE TARIFF DESIGNS

机译:能源合作关税设计中的交叉补贴

获取原文

摘要

OverviewReducing carbon footprint due to sustainability concerns has motivated energy efficiency and replacing fossil fuelbasedgeneration for renewable energy sources, some as distributed decentralized units (D-RES). This decentralizedenergy generation creates a new paradigm in the electricity grid, that of a conventional energy consumer turnedproducer (a “prosumerâ€). Prosumers require an enabler to provide energy use locally and remove unnecessaryenergy trading with a remote central point. This can be accomplished through forming “microgridsâ€, which providethe physical infrastructure as well as information exchange platform to control such a system. Microgrids aresometimes managed via an “energy cooperativeâ€, which is a decentralized, democratic coordination method,examples of which exist in Germany (Yildiz et al. 2015).Energy cooperatives require new tariffs designs for pricing their electricity use. Traditional tariff designs assumepassive consumers as end-users, but this assumption does not hold for cooperatives with D-RES volumes. Thus, theyrequire a new tariff design to match electricity supply and demand (Picciariello et al. 2015). Particularly,conventional tariffs designed for passive consumers can cause cross-subsidization, i.e. the subsidizing of electricityuse by one group of consumers for another group. In the case of high distributed solar PV generation, there isalready evidence from California, US, and New South Wales, Australia, that cross-subsidization probably happensfrom high-income to low-income households (Borenstein 2015; Simshauser 2016). These studies looked at crosssubsidizationunder net metering, where consumption and generation is metered as one connection. However, insome jurisdictions generation and consumption are metered and accounted separately. We investigate crosssubsidizationamounts in such scenarios.We investigate cross-subsidization in an energy cooperative developed from household data from Austin, Texas,US. We assume that all cooperative households have a PV panel and their energy generation and consumption ismetered separately. We first calculate cross-subsidization under a conventional tariff, drawn from a localmunicipality utility. We next find cross-subsidization values if the tariff were to match actual electricity costs. Ourresults show that current tariffs create massive amounts of cross-subsidization, which are probably by-products ofthe energy efficiency policy baked into the conventional tariff’s design. However, additional cross-subsidizationexists, which can be reduced with new tariffs based on hourly metering.MethodsWe use data from the Pecan Street Dataport1 for the full year of 2016. 150 households contained usable data for thisstudy and were all utilized. These households have separate metering and accounting for PV panel generation andconsumption. Electricity costs generally consist of energy costs, capacity costs, and other miscellaneous costs. We assume that thelatter depends only on the number of households connected and thus does not depend on tariff design. Currently,these households can be subscribed to Austin Energy’s residential tariff. This tariff is a volumetric tariff based solely on monthly energy use designed to promote frugal energy consumption. There is also a separate Value-of-Solarcredit for solar PV panel owners. To compare, we design a set of additional tariffs that price electricity not onlybased on energy use, but also capacity use (Table 1). Energy costs were based on ERCOT real-time locationalmarginal prices (RTLMP) 3. Capacity costs are assumed as that of a commercial entity of similar size4. Lastly, wedefine cross-subsidizaton for each household as the ratio between electricity costs per annum for a given tariff (ctariff)and the actual electricity delivery costs (creal): ğ¶ = ğ‘ğ‘¡ğ‘ğ‘Ÿğ‘–ğ‘“𑓠− ğ‘ğ‘Ÿğ‘’ğ‘ğ‘™/ğ‘ğ‘Ÿğ‘’ğ‘ğ‘™The same calculations are also done separately for electricity generation as credits per annum. All tariffs are calibratedto be revenue-neutral.ResultsWe find that there is significant cross-subsidization under theconventional tariff. This is mainly as a result of volumetrictariffing based solely on electricity use, designed to discourageexcess consumption. Compared to a flat rate with similarrevenue, this tariff creates heavy cross-subsidization (Figure 1,top). However, this is often from high energy users to lightenergy users. Thus, such cross-subsidization is not the maindiscussion topic here.Next, we compare cross-subsidization between the flat-rate,TOU, and RTP tariffs. For consumption, the TOU tariffgreatly reduces the cross-subsidization already and there isminimal gains from implementing an RTP tariff (Figure 1,middle). However, for generation, credits change drasticallybetween the TOU tariff and RTP tariff (Figure 1, bottom).This is because the TOU tariff contains two tiers, one of whichis the only one used by generation, which is only active atdaytime. Hence, it appears as a flat-rate tariff for generation.ConclusionsReducing the cross-subsidization of a flat-rate tariff requiresupdating metering and accounting from a monthly period to anhourly period, and also separating capacity costs from energycosts. The Cross-subsidization can be mostly mitigated withan RTP tariff. Cross-subsidization amounts are also muchlower than previously found in net metering scenarios(Simshauser 2016; Borenstein 2015).
机译:概述 由于对可持续性的关注而减少碳足迹,促进了能源效率并取代了以矿物燃料为基础的燃料。 可再生能源的发电,有些是分布式分散单位(D-RES)。分散的 能源产生在电网中创造了新的范式,传统的能源消费者 生产者(“生产者”)。生产者需要使能者在本地提供能源使用并消除不必要的能源 与偏远中心点进行能源交易。这可以通过形成“微电网”来实现, 物理基础设施以及用于控制此类系统的信息交换平台。微电网是 有时通过“能源合作社”进行管理,这是一种分散的,民主的协调方式, 德国的例子(Yildiz et al。2015)。 能源合作社要求采用新的电价设计来对用电进行定价。传统的关税设计假设 被动消费者作为最终用户,但这种假设不适用于D-RES量的合作社。因此,他们 要求采用新的电价设计以匹配电力供应和需求(Picciariello等人,2015)。特别, 专为被动用户设计的常规电价会导致交叉补贴,即电费补贴 一组消费者用于另一组。在高分布式太阳能光伏发电的情况下, 美国加利福尼亚和澳大利亚新南威尔士州已经有证据表明可能发生交叉补贴 从高收入家庭到低收入家庭(Borenstein 2015; Simshauser 2016)。这些研究着眼于交叉补贴 在净计量下,将消耗量和发电量作为一个连接进行计量。但是,在 一些辖区的发电量和消费量分别计量和核算。我们调查交叉补贴 在这种情况下的金额。 我们调查了根据得克萨斯州奥斯丁市的家庭数据开发的一家能源合作社的交叉补贴, 我们。我们假设所有合作家庭都有一块光伏板,其能源产生和消耗为 分开计量。我们首先计算从当地获得的常规关税下的交叉补贴 市政公用事业。接下来,如果电价与实际电费相匹配,我们将找到交叉补贴值。我们的 结果表明,当前的关税会产生大量的交叉补贴,这很可能是关税的副产品。 将能源效率政策纳入常规关税的设计中。但是,额外的交叉补贴 存在,可以通过基于小时计费的新费率降低此费用。 方法 我们使用2016年全年Pecan Street Dataport1的数据。其中有150户家庭包含了可用数据 研究,并被全部利用。这些家庭有单独的计量和核算,以用于光伏电池板的发电和 消耗。电力成本通常包括能源成本,容量成本和其他杂项成本。我们假设 后者仅取决于所连接的家庭数量,因此不取决于费率设计。目前, 这些家庭可以订阅Austin Energy的住宅费率。该费率是仅基于每月能源使用量的容积式费率,旨在促进节俭能源消耗。还有一个单独的太阳能价值 太阳能光伏板所有者的信用。相比之下,我们设计了一套额外的电价,不仅可以对电价进行定价 基于能源使用,但也取决于容量使用(表1)。能源成本基于ERCOT实时位置 边际价格(RTLMP)3.容量成本假定为规模相似的商业实体的成本4。最后,我们 将每个家庭的交叉补贴定义为给定电价(ctariff)下每年的电费之间的比率 以及实际的电费(creal):ğ¶= ğ'ğ'¡ğ'ğ'Ÿğ'–ğ'“ğ'” âˆ'ğ'ğ'Ÿğ''ğ'ğ'™/ğ'ğ' Ÿğ''ğ'ğ'™ 对于发电量,每年也要分别进行相同的计算。所有关税均已校准 保持收入中立。 结果 我们发现,在 常规关税。这主要是由于体积 仅基于用电量的电价,旨在阻止 多余的消费。与类似的固定费用相比 收入,此关税会产生大量的交叉补贴(图1, 最佳)。但是,这通常是从高能量用户到轻型 能源使用者。因此,这种交叉补贴不是主要的 在这里讨论话题。 接下来,我们比较固定费率之间的交叉补贴, TOU和RTP关税。对于消费,TOU费率 已经大大减少了交叉补贴,并且有 实施RTP关税带来的最小收益(图1, 中间)。然而,对于一代人来说,信用额度发生了巨大变化 在TOU关税和RTP关税之间(图1,底部)。 这是因为TOU资费包含两个等级, 其中之一 是世代使用的唯一一个,仅在 白天。因此,它似乎是发电的固定费率电价。 结论 减少统一费率的交叉补贴要求 将计费和计费从每月更新为 每小时的时间,并且还将产能成本与能源分开 费用。交叉补贴可以通过以下方式大大缓解 RTP关税。交叉补贴的金额也很多 比以前在净计量方案中发现的要低 (Simshauser 2016; Borenstein 2015)。

著录项

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号